Thursday, March 4, 2010

Net Neutrality Would Increase Likelihood of Content Discrimination, Phoenix Center Says

"Net neutrality regulation is motivated fundamentally by the belief that broadband service providers will,
at some future date, seek to extract profits from the content segment of the Internet marketplace, and
net neutrality aims to stop it," says a new white paper issued by George S. Ford, Phoenix Center for
Advanced Legal and Economic Public Policy Studies chief economist, and Michael Stern, Assistant
Professor of Economics at Auburn University.

Net neutrality supporters that fear surplus profit extraction will take the form of “exclusionary” practices
such as unfair or discriminatory access prices, “fast lanes” and “slow lanes” where preferential delivery is given to content firms willing and able to pay more, or outright monopolization of content, the authors say.

Such concerns about business advantage, whether "unfair" or not, are different from the separate issue of whether currently-envisioned network neutrality rules actually provide incentives to engage in such behavior, the authors say.

Some observers might be shocked to learn that net neutrality rules could actually encourage such
business behavior, not restrain it.

In fact, the latest Phoenix Center analysis suggests that net neutrality regulation actually increases
incentives to engage in exclusionary conduct in the content sector.

"Firms always have an incentive to take those steps, which increase their profits," the authors say.
"Ironically, net neutrality rules, which are supposed to suppress privately profitable exclusionary conduct,
will actually have an effect opposite of what is intended."

Because net neutrality regulations now under consideration will not reduce the profits associated with monopolization of content, but only those associated with the participation in a competitive content market, the proposed rule encourages broadband service providers to take steps to reduce the diversity of voices on the Internet to the detriment of the public interest, Ford and Stern argue.

The point is that network neutrality rules impose pricing rules, and the issue is whether such
pricing rules are likely to encourage or discourage business policies that increase or restrict content
options.

An important question is whether or not the proposed price regulations “promote consumer
choice and competition among providers of lawful content, applications, and services” by
addressing an ISP’s alleged motivation “to exclude independent producers of applications,
content, or portals from their networks.”

The answer is “no,” the authors say. "Net neutrality rules of the type proposed by the FCC and the
Markey-Eshoo Bill encourage exclusionary behavior rather than impede it."

The policy implications of this analysis are numerous, but can be summarized at a very
high level as follows: the analytical foundation for net neutrality remains in its infancy and the
concept needs more time to evolve, the authors argue.

Since even the advocates of net neutrality regulation admit that there exists a “de facto net neutrality
regime” today, there seems to be little reason for a headlong rush into bright-line regulatory
rules when so little is known about the issue.

The rules proposed by both the FCC and Congress create incentives that may not even exist absent the regulation, and increase whatever incentives do exist for ISPs to behave badly in the content market.

Most troubling about the proposed rules is that net neutrality, it now appears, has become little
more than a quibble over profits between providers, a far cry from the origins of the concept wherein the focus was on the freedom to distribute and consume information without undue interference.

source

No comments:

Will AI Actually Boost Productivity and Consumer Demand? Maybe Not

A recent report by PwC suggests artificial intelligence will generate $15.7 trillion in economic impact to 2030. Most of us, reading, seein...